guide:Bd39ad92b7: Difference between revisions

From Stochiki
No edit summary
 
mNo edit summary
 
(One intermediate revision by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
   
A '''risk measure''' is used to determine the amount of an asset or set of assets to be kept in reserve. The purpose of this reserve is to make the downside risk taken by financial institutions, such as banks and insurance companies, acceptable to regulators.
 
==Mathematical Definition==
 
A risk measure is defined as a mapping from a set of random variables to the real numbers. This set of random variables represents portfolio returns. The common notation for a risk measure associated with a random variable <math>X</math> is <math>\rho(X)</math>. A risk measure should have certain properties:<ref name="Artzner">{{cite journal|last=Artzner|first=Philippe|last2=Delbaen|first2=Freddy|last3=Eber|first3=Jean-Marc|last4=Heath|first4=David|year=1999|title=Coherent Measures of Risk|journal=Mathematical Finance|volume=9|issue=3|pages=203–228|url=http://www.math.ethz.ch/~delbaen/ftp/preprints/CoherentMF.pdf|doi=10.1111/1467-9965.00068}}</ref>
 
; Normalized
<math display="block">\rho(0) = 0</math>
That is, the risk of holding no assets is zero.
 
; Translative
<math display="block">\mathrm{If}\; a \in \mathbb{R},\;\mathrm{then}\; \rho(Z + a) = \rho(Z) - a</math>
 
The portofolio <math> A</math> is just adding cash <math>a</math> to your portfolio <math>Z</math>. In particular, if  <math>a=\rho(Z)</math> then <math>\rho(Z+A)=0</math>. In financial risk management, translation invariance implies that the addition of a sure amount of capital reduces the risk by the same amount.
 
; Monotone
<math display="block">\mathrm{If} \; Z_1 \leq Z_2 ,\; \mathrm{then} \; \rho(Z_2) \leq \rho(Z_1)</math>
 
That is, if portfolio <math>Z_2</math> always has better values than portfolio <math>Z_1</math> under [[almost surely|almost all]] scenarios then the risk of <math>Z_2</math> should be less than the risk of <math>Z_1</math>.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Wilmott|first=P.|year=2006|title=Quantitative Finance|publisher=Wiley|edition=2|volume=1|page=342}}</ref> E.g. If <math>Z_1</math> is an in the money call option (or otherwise) on a stock, and <math>Z_2</math> is also an in the money call option with a lower strike price.
In financial risk management, monotonicity implies a portfolio with greater future returns has less risk.
 
==Coherent Risk Measures==
 
A '''coherent risk measure''' is a risk measure that satisfies properties of [[Sub-additive|sub-additivity]] and [[homogeneity (statistics)|homogeneity]].
 
; Sub-additivity
 
<math display="block"> \rho(Z_1 + Z_2) \leq \rho(Z_1) + \rho(Z_2)</math>
 
The risk of two portfolios together cannot get any worse than adding the two risks separately: this is the [[Diversification (finance)|diversification]] principle. In financial risk management, sub-additivity implies diversification is beneficial. 
 
; Positive homogeneity
 
<math display="block">\mathrm{If}\; \alpha \ge 0,\; \mathrm{then} \; \rho(\alpha Z) = \alpha \rho(Z)</math>
 
Loosely speaking, if you double your portfolio then you double your risk. In financial risk management, positive homogeneity implies the risk of a position is proportional to its size.
 
===Convex risk measures===
 
The notion of coherence has been subsequently relaxed. Indeed, the notions of sub-additivity and positive homogeneity can be replaced by the notion of [[convex function|convexity]]:<ref>{{cite journal|last=Föllmer|first=H.|last2=Schied|first2=A.|year=2002|title=Convex measures of risk and trading constraints|journal=Finance and Stochastics|volume=6|issue=4|pages=429–447|doi=10.1007/s007800200072}}</ref>
; Convexity
 
<math display="block">\text{If } \lambda \in [0,1] \text{ then } \rho(\lambda Z_1 + (1-\lambda) Z_2) \leq \lambda \rho(Z_1) + (1-\lambda) \rho(Z_2)</math>
 
==VaR and TVaR==
 
'''Value at Risk (VaR)''' is a measure of the risk of investments. It estimates how much a set of investments might lose, given normal market conditions, in a set time period such as a day. VaR is typically used by firms and regulators in the financial industry to gauge the amount of assets needed to cover possible losses.
 
In [[financial mathematics|financial mathematics]] and [[financial risk management|financial risk management]], VaR is defined as: for a given portfolio, time horizon, and probability <math>p</math>, the <math>p</math> VaR is defined as a threshold loss value, such that the probability that the loss on the portfolio over the given time horizon exceeds this value is <math>p</math>.
 
For example, if a portfolio of stocks has a one-day 5% VaR of $1 million, that means that there is a 0.05 probability that the portfolio will fall in value by more than $1 million over a one-day period if there is no trading. Informally, a loss of $1 million or more on this portfolio is expected on 1 day out of 20 days (because of 5% probability). A loss which exceeds the VaR threshold is termed a "VaR break."<ref name="Holton">Holton, Glyn A. (2014). ''[http://value-at-risk.net Value-at-Risk: Theory and Practice]'' second edition, e-book.</ref>
 
'''Tail value at risk''' ('''TVaR'''), also known as '''tail conditional expectation''' ('''TCE''') or '''conditional tail expectation''' ('''CTE'''), is a [[risk measure|risk measure]] associated with VaR. It quantifies the expected value of the loss given that an event outside a given probability level has occurred. Unlike VaR, TVaR accounts for the severity of the failure, not only the chance of failure.
 
=== Details ===
 
Common parameters for VaR are 1% and 5% probabilities and one day and two week horizons, although other combinations are in use.<ref name="Pearson">{{cite book|first=Neil|last=Pearson|title=Risk Budgeting: Portfolio Problem Solving with Value-at-Risk|publisher=John Wiley & Sons|year=2002|isbn=978-0-471-40556-6}}</ref>
 
The probability level is about equally often specified as one minus the probability of a VaR break, so that the VaR in the example above would be called a one-day 95% VaR instead of one-day 5% VaR. This generally does not lead to confusion because the probability of VaR breaks is almost always small, certainly less than 50%.<ref name="Jorion">{{cite book|last=Jorion|first=Philippe|title=Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk|edition=3rd|publisher=McGraw-Hill|year=2006|isbn=978-0-07-146495-6}}</ref>
 
Although it virtually always represents a loss, VaR is conventionally reported as a positive number. A negative VaR would imply the portfolio has a high probability of making a profit, for example a one-day 5% VaR of negative $1 million implies the portfolio has a 95% chance of making more than $1 million over the next day.<ref name="Crouhy">{{cite book|first1=Michel|last1=Crouhy|first2=Dan|last2=Galai|first3=Robert|last3=Mark|title=The Essentials of Risk Management|publisher=McGraw-Hill|year=2001|isbn=978-0-07-142966-5}}</ref>
 
=== Mathematical definitions ===
 
Given a confidence level <math>\alpha \in (0,1)</math>, the VaR of the portfolio at the confidence level <math>\alpha</math> is given by the smallest number <math>l</math> such that the probability that the loss <math>L</math> exceeds <math>l</math> is at most <math>(1-\alpha)</math>.<ref name="McNeil">{{cite book|first1=Alexander|last1=McNeil|first2=Rüdiger|last2=Frey|first3=Paul|last3=Embrechts|title=Quantitative Risk Management: Concepts Techniques and Tools|publisher=Princeton University Press|year=2005|isbn=978-0-691-12255-7}}</ref>Mathematically, if <math>L</math> is the loss of a portfolio, then <math>\operatorname{VaR}_{\alpha}(L)</math> is the level <math>\alpha</math>-[[quantile|quantile]], i.e.
 
<math display="block">\operatorname{VaR}_\alpha(L)=\inf\{l \in \mathbb{R}:\operatorname{P}(L > l) \le 1-\alpha\}=\inf\{l\in \mathbb{R}:F_L(l) \ge \alpha\}.</math>
 
<ref>{{cite journal|last=Artzner|first=Philippe|last2=Delbaen|first2=Freddy|last3=Eber|first3=Jean-Marc|last4=Heath|first4=David|year=1999|title=Coherent Measures of Risk|journal=Mathematical Finance|volume=9|issue=3|pages=203–228|url=http://www.math.ethz.ch/~delbaen/ftp/preprints/CoherentMF.pdf|format=pdf|doi=10.1111/1467-9965.00068}}</ref>
 
Given a random variable <math>L</math> which is the loss of a portfolio at some future time and given a parameter <math>0 < \alpha < 1</math> then the tail value at risk is defined by <ref name=Artzner/>
 
<math display="block">
 
\operatorname{TVaR}_{\alpha}(L) = \frac{\left(F_L(v_{\alpha}) - \alpha \right)v_{\alpha} + \left(1- F_L(v_{\alpha})\right)\operatorname{E}[L \mid L > v_{\alpha} ]}{1 - \alpha},\hspace{5 pt} v_{\alpha} = \operatorname{VaR}_{\alpha}(L).
 
</math>
 
Note the following:
 
*The VaR is not a coherent risk measure since it violates the sub-additivity property.
*<math>v_{\alpha} \leq \operatorname{TVaR}_{\alpha}(L)</math> with equality if and only if <math>\operatorname{P}(L > v_{\alpha}) =  0 </math>, i.e., the two risk measures are equal whenever the loss is bounded (almost surely) by the VaR.
*When the distribution of the losses, <math>F_{L}</math>, is continuous at <math>v_{\alpha}</math>, then <math>\operatorname{TVaR}</math> reduces to <math> \operatorname{E}\left[L \mid L >  v_{\alpha}\right]</math>.
 
 
If the loss distribution is ''continuous'' then the formula for the TVaR can be expressed in terms of ''limited expected values'':
 
<math display="block">
 
\begin{align*}
 
\operatorname{TVaR}_{\alpha}(L) &= \operatorname{E}\left[L \mid L \gt  v_{\alpha}\right]  \\
 
&= v_{\alpha} + \frac{1}{1 - \alpha}  \left (\operatorname{E}[L] - \operatorname{E}[L \wedge v_{\alpha}]. \right )
 
\end{align*}
 
</math>
 
== Notes ==
<references/>
 
== References ==
*{{cite web |url = https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Risk_measure&oldid=918003240  | title= Risk measure | author = Wikipedia contributors | website= Wikipedia |publisher= Wikipedia |access-date = 27 September 2019 }}
*{{cite web |url = https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Value_at_risk&oldid=890152212  | title= Value at risk | author = Wikipedia contributors | website= Wikipedia |publisher= Wikipedia |access-date = 1 June 2019 }}
*{{cite web |url =  https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Tail_value_at_risk&oldid=883354913 | title= Tail value at risk | author = Wikipedia contributors | website= Wikipedia |publisher= Wikipedia |access-date = 1 June 2019 }}

Latest revision as of 22:38, 6 April 2024

A risk measure is used to determine the amount of an asset or set of assets to be kept in reserve. The purpose of this reserve is to make the downside risk taken by financial institutions, such as banks and insurance companies, acceptable to regulators.

Mathematical Definition

A risk measure is defined as a mapping from a set of random variables to the real numbers. This set of random variables represents portfolio returns. The common notation for a risk measure associated with a random variable [math]X[/math] is [math]\rho(X)[/math]. A risk measure should have certain properties:[1]

Normalized

[[math]]\rho(0) = 0[[/math]]

That is, the risk of holding no assets is zero.

Translative

[[math]]\mathrm{If}\; a \in \mathbb{R},\;\mathrm{then}\; \rho(Z + a) = \rho(Z) - a[[/math]]

The portofolio [math] A[/math] is just adding cash [math]a[/math] to your portfolio [math]Z[/math]. In particular, if [math]a=\rho(Z)[/math] then [math]\rho(Z+A)=0[/math]. In financial risk management, translation invariance implies that the addition of a sure amount of capital reduces the risk by the same amount.

Monotone

[[math]]\mathrm{If} \; Z_1 \leq Z_2 ,\; \mathrm{then} \; \rho(Z_2) \leq \rho(Z_1)[[/math]]

That is, if portfolio [math]Z_2[/math] always has better values than portfolio [math]Z_1[/math] under almost all scenarios then the risk of [math]Z_2[/math] should be less than the risk of [math]Z_1[/math].[2] E.g. If [math]Z_1[/math] is an in the money call option (or otherwise) on a stock, and [math]Z_2[/math] is also an in the money call option with a lower strike price. In financial risk management, monotonicity implies a portfolio with greater future returns has less risk.

Coherent Risk Measures

A coherent risk measure is a risk measure that satisfies properties of sub-additivity and homogeneity.

Sub-additivity

[[math]] \rho(Z_1 + Z_2) \leq \rho(Z_1) + \rho(Z_2)[[/math]]

The risk of two portfolios together cannot get any worse than adding the two risks separately: this is the diversification principle. In financial risk management, sub-additivity implies diversification is beneficial.

Positive homogeneity

[[math]]\mathrm{If}\; \alpha \ge 0,\; \mathrm{then} \; \rho(\alpha Z) = \alpha \rho(Z)[[/math]]

Loosely speaking, if you double your portfolio then you double your risk. In financial risk management, positive homogeneity implies the risk of a position is proportional to its size.

Convex risk measures

The notion of coherence has been subsequently relaxed. Indeed, the notions of sub-additivity and positive homogeneity can be replaced by the notion of convexity:[3]

Convexity

[[math]]\text{If } \lambda \in [0,1] \text{ then } \rho(\lambda Z_1 + (1-\lambda) Z_2) \leq \lambda \rho(Z_1) + (1-\lambda) \rho(Z_2)[[/math]]

VaR and TVaR

Value at Risk (VaR) is a measure of the risk of investments. It estimates how much a set of investments might lose, given normal market conditions, in a set time period such as a day. VaR is typically used by firms and regulators in the financial industry to gauge the amount of assets needed to cover possible losses.

In financial mathematics and financial risk management, VaR is defined as: for a given portfolio, time horizon, and probability [math]p[/math], the [math]p[/math] VaR is defined as a threshold loss value, such that the probability that the loss on the portfolio over the given time horizon exceeds this value is [math]p[/math].

For example, if a portfolio of stocks has a one-day 5% VaR of $1 million, that means that there is a 0.05 probability that the portfolio will fall in value by more than $1 million over a one-day period if there is no trading. Informally, a loss of $1 million or more on this portfolio is expected on 1 day out of 20 days (because of 5% probability). A loss which exceeds the VaR threshold is termed a "VaR break."[4]

Tail value at risk (TVaR), also known as tail conditional expectation (TCE) or conditional tail expectation (CTE), is a risk measure associated with VaR. It quantifies the expected value of the loss given that an event outside a given probability level has occurred. Unlike VaR, TVaR accounts for the severity of the failure, not only the chance of failure.

Details

Common parameters for VaR are 1% and 5% probabilities and one day and two week horizons, although other combinations are in use.[5]

The probability level is about equally often specified as one minus the probability of a VaR break, so that the VaR in the example above would be called a one-day 95% VaR instead of one-day 5% VaR. This generally does not lead to confusion because the probability of VaR breaks is almost always small, certainly less than 50%.[6]

Although it virtually always represents a loss, VaR is conventionally reported as a positive number. A negative VaR would imply the portfolio has a high probability of making a profit, for example a one-day 5% VaR of negative $1 million implies the portfolio has a 95% chance of making more than $1 million over the next day.[7]

Mathematical definitions

Given a confidence level [math]\alpha \in (0,1)[/math], the VaR of the portfolio at the confidence level [math]\alpha[/math] is given by the smallest number [math]l[/math] such that the probability that the loss [math]L[/math] exceeds [math]l[/math] is at most [math](1-\alpha)[/math].[8]Mathematically, if [math]L[/math] is the loss of a portfolio, then [math]\operatorname{VaR}_{\alpha}(L)[/math] is the level [math]\alpha[/math]-quantile, i.e.

[[math]]\operatorname{VaR}_\alpha(L)=\inf\{l \in \mathbb{R}:\operatorname{P}(L \gt l) \le 1-\alpha\}=\inf\{l\in \mathbb{R}:F_L(l) \ge \alpha\}.[[/math]]

[9]

Given a random variable [math]L[/math] which is the loss of a portfolio at some future time and given a parameter [math]0 \lt \alpha \lt 1[/math] then the tail value at risk is defined by [1]

[[math]] \operatorname{TVaR}_{\alpha}(L) = \frac{\left(F_L(v_{\alpha}) - \alpha \right)v_{\alpha} + \left(1- F_L(v_{\alpha})\right)\operatorname{E}[L \mid L \gt v_{\alpha} ]}{1 - \alpha},\hspace{5 pt} v_{\alpha} = \operatorname{VaR}_{\alpha}(L). [[/math]]

Note the following:

  • The VaR is not a coherent risk measure since it violates the sub-additivity property.
  • [math]v_{\alpha} \leq \operatorname{TVaR}_{\alpha}(L)[/math] with equality if and only if [math]\operatorname{P}(L \gt v_{\alpha}) = 0 [/math], i.e., the two risk measures are equal whenever the loss is bounded (almost surely) by the VaR.
  • When the distribution of the losses, [math]F_{L}[/math], is continuous at [math]v_{\alpha}[/math], then [math]\operatorname{TVaR}[/math] reduces to [math] \operatorname{E}\left[L \mid L \gt v_{\alpha}\right][/math].


If the loss distribution is continuous then the formula for the TVaR can be expressed in terms of limited expected values:

[[math]] \begin{align*} \operatorname{TVaR}_{\alpha}(L) &= \operatorname{E}\left[L \mid L \gt v_{\alpha}\right] \\ &= v_{\alpha} + \frac{1}{1 - \alpha} \left (\operatorname{E}[L] - \operatorname{E}[L \wedge v_{\alpha}]. \right ) \end{align*} [[/math]]

Notes

  1. 1.0 1.1 Artzner, Philippe (1999). "Coherent Measures of Risk". Mathematical Finance 9 (3): 203–228. doi:10.1111/1467-9965.00068. 
  2. Wilmott, P. (2006). "Quantitative Finance" 1. Wiley. 
  3. Föllmer, H. (2002). "Convex measures of risk and trading constraints". Finance and Stochastics 6 (4): 429–447. doi:10.1007/s007800200072. 
  4. Holton, Glyn A. (2014). Value-at-Risk: Theory and Practice second edition, e-book.
  5. Pearson, Neil (2002). Risk Budgeting: Portfolio Problem Solving with Value-at-Risk. John Wiley & Sons. ISBN 978-0-471-40556-6.
  6. Jorion, Philippe (2006). Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk (3rd ed.). McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-146495-6.
  7. Crouhy, Michel; Galai, Dan; Mark, Robert (2001). The Essentials of Risk Management. McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-142966-5.
  8. McNeil, Alexander; Frey, Rüdiger; Embrechts, Paul (2005). Quantitative Risk Management: Concepts Techniques and Tools. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-12255-7.
  9. Artzner, Philippe (1999). "Coherent Measures of Risk" (pdf). Mathematical Finance 9 (3): 203–228. doi:10.1111/1467-9965.00068. 

References

  • Wikipedia contributors. "Risk measure". Wikipedia. Wikipedia. Retrieved 27 September 2019.
  • Wikipedia contributors. "Value at risk". Wikipedia. Wikipedia. Retrieved 1 June 2019.
  • Wikipedia contributors. "Tail value at risk". Wikipedia. Wikipedia. Retrieved 1 June 2019.